Preview only show first 10 pages with watermark. For full document please download

Health Inequality In India: Evidence From Nfhs 3

Health inequality in india: evidence from NFHS 3

   EMBED


Share

Transcript

  Special article Economic & Political Weekly   EPW august 2, 2008 41 Halth inqualty n inda: evdn from NFHS 3 William Joe, U S Mishra, K Navaneetham R  ecent research has witnessed considerable engagement with the task o comprehending the crucial determinantso health outcomes. It is observed that the burden o illhealth is borne disproportionately by dierent populationsubgroups and that people o lower socio-economic status consist-ently experience poor health outcomes [Macinko et al 2003].Several empirical studies have also acknowledged such income-related inequalities in health, propounded as the absolute incomehypothesis [Kakwani et al 1997; van Doorslaer et al 1997:Humphries and van Doorslaer 2000]. In view o such ndings,health promotion o the poor has emerged worldwide as a vitalarea or policy research and action. Policy initiatives andprogrammes strongly perceive that inequalities in the healthoutcomes o dierent population subgroups are characterised by certain systematic deprivations (such as poverty). Apparently, some o the Indian health policies and program-mes also attempt to eliminate deprivation in the provisioning o healthcare and achieve the objective o health equity. 1 In order toachieve this objective, it is important to steer policymakingthrough timely and systematic assessment o prevailing healthinequality, 2 a task that so ar does not seem to have receivedserious attention. Although a ew studies have presented region-specic or population-subgroup-related health proles or India,they are at best able only to refect on disparities and not inequa-lities. While disparities are evaluated based on the positioningaround aggregate outcome, inequalities have to be adjudgedaccording to specic ethical or economic ideals. Moreover, orensuring equitable and ecient allocation o public healthresources, it is imperative to unravel the depth and the varieddimensions o health outcomes, especially through measuressensitised or equity concerns. Apart rom these considerations, itis also o analytical interest to examine whether income inequa-lity itsel poses as a public health hazard. This question hasgained much academic attention but most o the ndings o studies 3 on the topic have remained inconclusive. The literatureon health economics, which identies this question as the relativeincome hypothesis states that the distribution o income in asociety has a larger impact on population’s health than absoluteincome. Since most o the studies on relative income hypothesisare undertaken in the context o developed countries, it would be worthwhile to gather some insights rom the Indian experienceto urther our understanding o the income-health nexus.In this article, we employ widely accepted measurementtechniques to assess inequities in child health across dierentIndian states and draw some interesting conclusions on therelationship between income inequality and health inequality inthe country. As we all know, health o children assumes The authors appreciate the editorial eort o P R G Nair towards makingthe manuscript read better.William Joe ( [email protected] ), U S Mishra ( [email protected] ) andK Navaneetham ( [email protected] ) are at the Centre or DevelopmentStudies, Thiruvananthapuram, Kerala. This article utilises the National Family Health Survey-3data and presents an empirical assessment of income-related health inequality in India. It undertakesa state-level analysis of inequities in child healthby employing the widely accepted measures of concentration curves and concentration indices. Itfinds that the poorer sections of the population arebeleaguered with ill health whether in the quest forchild survival or due to anxieties pertaining to childnutrition. Further, an attempt is made to comprehendthe relationship between income inequality andhealth status in the Indian context. The analysis revealsthat the degree of health inequalities escalates whenthe rising average income levels of the populationare accompanied by rising income inequalities. Theincome-poor sections have different needs andtherefore, planning and intervention necessitatesan understanding of the sources of inequality andrecognition of the vulnerable groups to arrive at efficientresource allocation and policy decisions.  Special article  august 2, 2008 EPW   Economic & Political Weekly 42 signicance or human and economic development o any country; but what is more important is to regard it as their rightto survival, protection, participation and development as ratiedby the government o India in 1989 through the Convention onthe Rights o the Child ( CRC ) drated by the United NationsCommission on Human Rights. Unortunately, most o the deathsrampant among children in India arepreventable and are caused by a combi-nation o under-nourishment and onslau-ght o inectious diseases. Although,child health and welare has been aprime item in the agenda o the centraland the state governments, their intentcannot proceed very ar in the absenceo a prior assessment o the magnitudeand varied dimensions o the problem.With the motivation to ll this void, therest o the paper is organised as ollows.Section 1 discusses the measurementtechniques employed to measure the magnitude o disparities inchild health status. Section 2 bries about the data sources andthe variables identied or the analysis. Section 3 presents theempirical ndings obtained or the income-related dimension o health inequality and section 4 attempts to interpret the resultstheoretically. Section 5 concludes the discussion and presents aew policy suggestions. 1 Mthods  As we already argued, the assessment o health status could beimproved by adopting certain distribution-sensitised measuresalong the identied dimensions. In order to examine income-related inequality, we adopt the standard technique o employingconcentration curves and concentration indices. Underlying thistechnique is a simple but interesting principle o dening equity.The principle involved stipulates that the cumulative proportionso ill health must match with the cumulative population sharesand any mismatch between the two sets is dened as inequity.The concentration curve ( CC ) and concentration index ( CI ) havecertain attractive properties compared to certain other measureso health disparities [Wagsta et al 1991, Kakwani et al 1997] andare employed here as a means or quantiying the degree o income-related inequality in certain specic health variables.The CC plots the cumulative proportions o the population (begin-ning with the most disadvantaged in terms o income and ending with the least disadvantaged) along the x-axis   against thecumulative proportions o ill healthplotted on the y-axis. For interpretativepurposes, i the burden o ill health wereequally distributed across socio-economicgroups, the CC would coincide with thediagonal. I poor health is concentratedin the lower socio-economic groups, thehealth CC would lie above the diagonal andthe arther the CC lies rom the diagonal,the greater would be the degree o inequality. The CI is dened as twice thearea between the CC and the diagonal.The CI provides a measure o the extento inequalities in health status that are systematically associated with socio-economic status. The CI can be easily computed by making use o the convenient covariance result [Kakwani 1980;Jenkins 1988; Lerman and Yitzhaki 1989] as ollows: CI = 2 cov ( H i , R  i )/μ, where H is the health variable whose inequality is being measu-red, μ is its mean, R  i is the i th individual’s ractional rank in thesocio-economic distribution and cov( H i , R  i ,.) is the covariance.The CI ranges between +1 and -1 and takes negative values whenthe CC lies above the line o equality, indicating disproportionateconcentration o the ill health outcome among the poor. 2 Data and Varabls Notwithstanding the measurement techniques, availability o health inormation disaggregated by population groups becomescrucial in evaluating health inequities. Prior to the advent o theNational Family Health Surveys ( NFHS ), health inormation wasrestricted to aggregate measures and it had been dicult to study the distribution pattern o health in the population. The genesiso the NFHS , its wide coverage and the nature o inormationcollected oer an exclusive opportunity to employ robustmeasures to comprehend health disparities across the Indianunion. In order to portray the status o health deprivation in Indiaand its spatial and group related dispersal, we utilise the unitlevel records o the third and the latest round o  NFHS (2005-06),conducted by the International Institute or Population Sciencesand ORC Macro. To retain the sensitivity o the health outcomeindicators, the domain o child health has been taken as a majorcriterion as it allows or better interventions right rom thepreliminary stages o lie. Thereore, in our analysis we engageourselves with child health outcome variables, across dierentstates o the Indian union. As the key indicators o child health, this paper employs theinormation available on under-ve mortalities, immunisationstatus and nutritional perormance (stunting and underweight)o the child population o the dierent states. For measuring theinequities in child undernutrition, we use the NFHS 3 inormation tabe 1: Defnons of chd Heah indaos Used Under-five mortality rate (U5MR) The number of deaths to children under five yearsof age per 1,000 live births. Figures are based onbirths during the five years preceding the survey.Stunting (H/A) Children whose height-for age is below minustwo standard deviations (-2 SD) from the medianof the reference population, are considered shortfor their age, or stunted.Underweight (W/A) Children whose weight-for-age measures arebelow minus two standard deviations (-2 SD)from the median of the reference population areunderweight for their age.Prevalence of anaemia(ANE) Children between six months and 59 monthsare classified as anaemic if the haemoglobinconcentration in them is found to be lower than11.0 g/dl.Not fully immunised (NFI) A child (12-23 months) is considered not fullyimmunised if the child has not received anyone of the following vaccinations, namely; BCG, ameasles vaccination, three DPT vaccinations, andthree polio vaccinations. Cumulative % of births ranked by economic status Fgue 1: Unde-Fve Moay conenaon cuves       C   u   m   u    l   a    t    i   v   e    %    o    f   u   n    d   e   r  -    f    i   v   e   m   o   r    t   a    l    i    t    i   e   s 1008060402000 20 40 60 80 100All IndiaMaharashtraGujaratMadhya PradeshEgalitarian Line  Special article Economic & Political Weekly   EPW august 2, 2008 43 provided on the basis o the new international reerence popula-tion released by World Health Organisation ( WHO ) in April 2006[ WHO Multicentre Growth Reerence Study Group 2006] andaccepted by the government o India [ IIPS and ORC Macro 2007]. All these variables are specically dened in Table 1 (p 42). Toocus attention on issues o association and causation, we haveobtained inormation also on three other economic variables:One, the state-wise net state domestic product ( NSDP ) 2004-05 atactor cost, which is obtained through the statistics published by Central Statistics Organisation ( CSO ). The second is the inormationon public spending on health as a share o total health spending, which is taken rom Rao et al (2005). In addition to these varia-bles we also required inormation on the income inequality levelsacross dierent Indian states. For this purpose we have used theunit level records o National Sample Survey’s ( NSS ) 61st roundon consumer expenditure. Here, the consumption expenditure o the households is taken as a proxy or income and we havecomputed the Gini coecient o inequality in per capita monthly consumption expenditure or all the states o India. 3 intrstat Dffrns n Halth inqualts In this section, we examine the magnitude o income-relatedinequalities in health, across the dierent Indian states. For thispurpose, we have computed the CI or the selected indicators o child health across all the Indian states (Table 2). The CI valuesor a range o child health indicators or the country as a wholeare negative, conrming the prevalence o income-related healthinequalities that are maniest primarily among the poor. Oncomparison o these inequalities across varied indicators o childhealth, inequalities are more pronounced in the case o the under-ve mortalities, in undernutrition and the receipt o basic vacci-nations or immunisation. The under-ve mortality  CC or all-In-dia as well as or three other major states (Maharashtra, Gujaratand Madhya Pradesh) with higher health inequality levels areshown in Figure 1 (p 42). All these CC s lie above the diagonal andthus, indicate a greater concentration o health eventualitiesamong the poorer groups.While the CI value or under-ve mortality at the national levelis computed to be (-0.1582), it presents a reasonably wide rangeacross various states with the minimum o (-0.0388) in West Bengaland maximum o (-0.4107) in Uttaranchal. Among the othermajor states, Maharashtra, Madhya Pradesh, Gujarat, Tamil Naduand Punjab experience greater income-related inequalities in under-ve mortality as against the states o Uttar Pradesh, Rajasthanand Bihar, which show much lower levels o inequalities. Apartrom the dierences in the magnitude o inequalities across theboard, the negative values indicate vulnerabilities among the poor.Other than under-ve mortality, similar inequality is assessedor a set o child health indicators, which include nutritionalmake-up, anaemia and child immunisation. As regards nutritio-nal make-up, the two dimensions namely stunting (low height-or-age) and the underweight (low weight-or-age) maniestinequalities at the all-India level ranging between (-0.1249) and(-0.1600). The all-India level inequality in weight-or-age basednutritional assessment being the largest depicts a similar patternacross states as well. Compared with stunting, the inequality innutrition according to the underweight criterion has a widerrange between (-0.0835) in Madhya Pradesh and (-0.3063) inGoa. The level o overall prevalence o the same could also condi-tion a moderate range o inequality across states or the alterna-tive nutritional measures. This is obvious rom the act thatprevalence o undernutrition according to the underweight crite-rion is by ar the largest when contrasted with the same evalua-ted on an alternative criterion like stunting. Further, weight-or-age in its own construct has a propensity or larger variationduring childhood. As regards stunting the all-India concentrationindex value is (-0.1249) with a variation range o (-0.0325) inMeghalaya and (-0.2867) in Goa. Not only is the range o varia-tion in this inequality measure relatively lower compared to thesame according to the underweight criterion but also the highinequality magnitudes are lesser in this case.For the indicator o anaemia the all-India CI value o (-0.0518)is observably lower and could be due to the widespread preva-lence o anaemia across the population but still the poorersections are ound to remain at a higher disadvantage. Theinequities in child-anaemia do not vary signicantly across themajor states. However, the states o Mizoram (-0.1,363), Goa(-0.1,126), West Bengal (-0.0919) and Orissa (-0.0851) are oundto be more inequitable. In addition to these health outcome tabe 2: ci fo inequaes n chd Heah indaos States CIU5MR CIANE CIH/A CIW/A CINFI Andhra Pradesh -0.0704 -0.0367 -0.1311 -0.1650 -0.0963Arunachal Pradesh -0.1401 -0.0587 -0.1167 -0.1816 -0.1296Assam -0.0541 -0.0581 -0.1302 -0.1373 -0.1079Bihar -0.0882 -0.0389 -0.0861 -0.0962 -0.1340Chhattisgarh -0.0764 -0.0389 -0.0669 -0.1133 -0.1443Delhi -0.1835 -0.0666 -0.1313 -0.1410 -0.2079Goa -0.1282 -0.1126 -0.2867 -0.3063 -0.2893Gujarat -0.2198 -0.0658 -0.1127 -0.1432 -0.1542Haryana -0.1304 -0.0524 -0.1408 -0.1260 -0.3341Himachal Pradesh -0.2186 -0.0406 -0.1305 -0.1323 -0.1589Jammu and Kashmir -0.1656 -0.0169 -0.1690 -0.2258 -0.2341Jharkhand -0.0546 -0.0624 -0.0803 -0.0876 -0.1131Karnataka -0.1325 -0.0339 -0.1284 -0.1648 -0.1823Kerala -0.1274 -0.0314 -0.1628 -0.2026 -0.2719Madhya Pradesh -0.2081 -0.0406 -0.0683 -0.0835 -0.1810Maharashtra -0.2481 -0.0444 -0.1427 -0.1796 -0.1795Manipur -0.3458 -0.0097 -0.1409 -0.1805 -0.1975Meghalaya -0.1152 -0.0525 -0.0325 -0.0811 -0.0957Mizoram -0.1942 -0.1363 -0.1606 -0.2400 -0.2130Nagaland -0.1646 NA -0.1328 -0.1645 -0.1113Orissa -0.0844 -0.0827 -0.1865 -0.1811 -0.1328Punjab -0.1688 -0.0331 -0.2082 -0.2597 -0.2505Rajasthan -0.0801 -0.0198 -0.1043 -0.1337 -0.0898Sikkim -0.0581 -0.0171 -0.0848 0.0200 -0.0725Tamil Nadu -0.1749 -0.0346 -0.1463 -0.1936 -0.0523Tripura -0.2251 -0.0381 -0.1113 -0.1421 -0.2306Uttar Pradesh -0.0960 -0.0271 -0.0885 -0.1181 -0.0754Uttaranchal -0.4107 -0.0710 -0.1924 -0.1997 -0.2302West Bengal -0.0388 -0.0919 -0.1716 -0.1660 -0.1231All India -0.1582 -0.0518 -0.1249 -0.1600 -0.1595 The CI ranges between +1 and -1 and takes negative (positive) values when the ill healthoutcomes are concentrated among the poor (rich).CIU5MR- (CI) for under-five mortality, CIANE- CI for anaemia, CIH/A- CI for stunting, CIW/A- CI forunderweight and CINFI- CI for not fully immunised.Source: Computed by authors using NFHS 3 (2005-06) unit level records.  Special article  august 2, 2008 EPW   Economic & Political Weekly 44 indicators, we have also tried to examine whether income-relatedinequities are present in the attainment o basic vaccinations, which is provided through the public health machinery. Apartrom the problem o lower rates o complete immunisation, thereare evidently higher income-related inequities inherent in thedistribution o non-immunised children across dierent states.Even in states with better coverage o primary healthcare (likeKerala), children belonging to poorer sections o the populationare at a greater disadvantage as the concentration o these incom-plete immunisations is higher among them. Undoubtedly, apartrom income, inequality in such outcomes is arising due to theinterplay o several actors including education and healthawareness and it would be an important and challenging task toprobe into inequalities obtained due to reasons other than theelementary issue o income deprivation. Ater providing a preliminary account o income-related childhealth inequality in India, we now turn to discuss the relationshipbetween health inequalities and income across dierent Indianstates. To acilitate the discussion, we have classied the die-rent states into our categories (Table 3). Employing the all-Indiagures o per capita NSDP (or income) and CI or under-vemortalities (or health inequality) 4 as a cut-o level, the statesare classied into “low income – low health inequality”, “lowincome – high health inequality”, “high income – low healthinequality” and “high income – high health inequality” onesdepending on whether their respective values exceed or all shorto the cut-o level. On this basis we are able to obtain vitalinsights into the relationship between themagnitudes o inequalities in health andthe state’s income prole. States like Punjab,Maharashtra and Gujarat demonstrate thecoexistence o higher levels o incomealong with higher levels o inequalities inunder-ve mortalities and states such asUttar Pradesh, Bihar and Orissa which havelower income levels are also ound to havelower levels o inequalities in under-vemortalities. These states suggest, that thereis a straightorward relationship betweenincome levels and health inequality. Butthere are other states such as MadhyaPradesh, Karnataka and Kerala, which are exceptions to such arelationship and suggest there is no such clear-cut relation.To probe urther, we bring in the element o income inequalitiesto comprehend the observed health inequities across these states.Inclusion o income inequality  5 into the analysis would signiy that the health inequality in a state is not only dependent on theoverall level o income but also on its distribution. This too is notsucient to explain the observed pattern o health inequalitiesacross dierent states. For example, consider major states such asKerala and Madhya Pradesh, which are exception to any suchdirect relationship. Both these states have higher levels o incomeinequalities coupled with varying levels o income and healthinequality (lower in Kerala and higher in Madhya Pradesh).Thereore, without asserting association any urther, we presenta simple model to better elucidate the expected relationshipbetween the two. 4 inom inqualty and Halth inqualty To understand health inequality through the income domain, weadopt a simple model discussed in Wagsta (2002, 1986). In thismodel, the relationship between health and medical care isassumed to be concave, meaning that medical care is subject todiminishing returns in the production o health. It suggests thatricher individuals are likely to end up with higher levels o healthand that increases in income inequality result in higher levels o health inequality. Further, it is inerred that i medical care issubsidised through public spending, it helps to lower the levels o health inequality. It also suggests increases in health inequality i rising incomes are accompanied by technological improvementsin healthcare. In order to veriy these predictions rom the model,an empirical analysis has also been attempted. This exerciseshows that neither income inequality nor the public share o health spending proves to be a signicant determinant o healthinequities but that average income o the population is signicantin determining the same. However, such ndings raise thequestion as to why these empirical ndings dier rom thetheoretical insights oered by the model. For instance, why arerising levels o income inequalities not accompanied with higherlevels o health inequality? In act, the interstate analysis to bediscussed later also provides us with similar results (Table 4, p 45).Does it imply that the supposedly strict concave relationshipbetween health and medical care is weak?To explore urther, we modiy theassumption o a strictly concave relation-ship between income and health andinstead work with a convex-concaverelationship (as shown in Figure 2)between income and health. This modiedassumption helps to elucidate relationshipbetween health and medical care expend-iture – particularly in a developingcountry – by capturing the indivisiblenature o health expenditure and tocomprehend health inequality in a strik-ing manner. What motivated us to engage with such a relationship are the acts thatin a developing country whenever an individual decides to seek medical care, his rst task would be to arrange or an array o healthcare-related expenses beginning rom travelling cost andmedical ees. Also, during the initial phases o the treatment process,oten, the individual is advised to undergo a ew diagnostic tests, tabe 3: cassfaon aodng o inome leves and Heah inequay Lower Health Inequality Higher Health Inequality Lower Arunachal Pradesh, Jammu and Kashmir, Madhya Pradeshincome Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Manipur, Mizoram, Nagaland,Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand, Tripura, UttaranchalMeghalaya, Orissa, Rajasthan,Uttar Pradesh, West BengalHigher Haryana, Goa, Karnataka, Kerala, Delhi, Gujarat, Himachal Pradesh,income Sikkim Maharashtra, Punjab, Tamil Nadu For income, per capita NSDP (2004-05, at factor cost) and for health inequality, CI of under-fivemortalities are used with their all-India levels employed as a cut off mark to classify the statesinto low and high categories. Fgue 2: inome-Heah reaonshp H 2 HealthIncomeY 1 Y 2 Y 3 Y 4 H 1 H 3 H 4  Special article Economic & Political Weekly   EPW august 2, 2008 45  which undoubtedly help detect the ailment accurately but impor-tantly require additional expenditure. It must be noticed that many such expenses are indivisible and unavoidable under conditionso eeble health systems as is the case in many developingcountries. Such specic diculties in accessing quality medicalcare provide inadequate (or lower) returns to health at low levelso income. This line o reasoning is conceived in terms o the initialconvex region o the income-health unction depicted in Figure 2.Under such a ramework, richer individuals are likely to endup with higher levels o health but it also suggests that individualincomes have to exceed a certain threshold (somewhere close to Y 3 ) to able to meet the initial expenditure requirements ormedical care in order to reap greater health benets. For instance,consider two individuals with incomes Y 1 and Y 2 respectively asshown in Figure 2. In the absolute sense, both these incomes arelow and thus, lead to low levels o health. But still, there exists acertain degree o income inequality between these individuals(absolute and relative income inequality, given by  Y 2 – Y 1 , Y 2  / Y 1 )that leads to health inequalities (given by  H 2 – H 1 , H 2  / H 1 ). It isimportant to note that the inequalities in health, both in absoluteand relative senses, are smaller than the inequalities observed inthe income distribution and suggest that at lower levels o income,health inequalities are also low. But i individuals are around thethreshold income level beyond which they would be able to aordbetter healthcare, then the relationship between income andhealth inequalities worsens. To demonstrate this act, considertwo individuals with incomes Y 3 and Y 4 respectively and allowor a considerable degree o income inequality between them(i e, Y 4 – Y 3 , Y 4  / Y 3 ). Here, unlike in the earlier case, we observethat despite similar degrees o income inequalities, the level o health inequality ( H 4 – H 3 , H 4  / H 3 ) has increased with increasein incomes.In a nutshell, the modication o the income-health unctionallows one to iner that or a given level o income inequality, i overall income levels are lower (higher) then health inequalitiesare also lower (higher). It also suggests that the levels o income inequality also have signicant bearing upon the extento health inequality but that the impact becomes more observablei the income inequalities are associated with higher levels o income. More importantly, under conditions o lower incomesand high-income inequality, the health inequality levels wouldget enhanced whereas i income levels are higher and incomeinequality levels are low, they would have a moderating impacton health inequality levels. Another related discussion that isrelevant here is the impact o public health spending uponhealth inequality. Although it is desirable that such acilitiesshould be distributed more evenly across the population, theactual result may be undesirable as health acilities providedthrough public health spending oten tend to be concentratedin particular regions such as urban areas or certain other target-locations thereby, oten ailing in guaranteeing universal access andopportunity. Any such bias in the provisioning o public healthcould thus worsen the distribution o health across individuals.In order to quickly veriy the predictions o these two dierentrameworks in the Indian context, a simple regression exercise isundertaken here. This analysis could also be viewed as apreliminary attempt to comprehend the dierences in healthinequality across the dierent states o India in terms o incomeinequality, per capita income and share o public health spending.We have selected the negative o the under-ve mortality  CI as anindicator o child health inequality. As explanatory variables, theGini measure o inequality in per capita monthly consumptionexpenditure is taken as a proxy or income inequality, per capita NSDP at actor cost is utilised to represent the state per capitaincome and public spending on health as a share o total healthspending is taken to represent the role o subsidies in healthcare.The results rom the regression analysis are presented in Table 4.Model 1 shows that in the Indian context, income inequality ispositively but insignicantly related with levels o healthinequality. The R-squared value suggests that hardly 2 per cent o the variations in health inequality are actually explained by thedierences in income inequalities. This nding is similar to whatWagsta (2002) nds while comprehending the dierences inhealth inequality across developing countries. Given the inability o income inequality alone to capture the variations in healthinequality, we add other important variables to comprehend thecausation. Specically, in model 2 we control or income inequality and public health spending levels and thereby attempt to elicitthe role o per capita income in determining health inequalities.The results endorse the view that increases in average incomealso increase the levels o health inequality as indicated by thepositive and signicant coecient o  NSDP per capita. Thetheoretical ramework discussed earlier has predicted thisrelationship. However, it is also observed that the coecientobtained or the variable o public health spending as a proportiono total health spending possesses a negative sign, suggesting itsavourable eect or reducing health inequalities. However, theeect turns out to be statistically insignicant.The overall results obtained here (in models 1 and 2), especially in relation to income inequality and average income, are partly inagreement with the ramework but do not lend any concretesupport to the relative income hypothesis. In other words, it may also be opined that the concave relationship between income andhealth is somewhat unable to capture the conditions prevalent indeveloping countries. Hence, now we go on to test the alternateramework namely o the convex-concave relationship between tabe 4: regesson resus fo cis of Unde-Fve Moay Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3Parameter Parameter Parameter(t-statistics) (t-statistics) (t-statistics) Constant 0.076 0.080 0.048(0.992) (0.920) (1.482)Gini coefficient 0.183 0.160(0.767) (-.0546)NSDP per capita 9.49E-06**(2.429)Public spending on health as % total -0.00012(-0.124)Avg of Gini and normalised NSDP per capita 0.211***(2.894)F statistic for model 0.588 2.438* 8.378***R-squared 0.024 0.249 0.267Adjusted R-squared -0.017 0.147 0.235N 26 26 25 *** Significant at the 1% level, ** significant at the 5% level.